What's holding back the world economy?
What's
holding back the world economy?
Joseph Stiglitz
Taken From: The Guardian
Seven years
after the global financial crisis erupted in 2008, the world economy continued
to stumble in 2015. According to the United Nations’ report World Economic
Situation and Prospects 2016, the average growth rate in developed economies
has declined by more than 54% since the crisis. An estimated 44 million people
are unemployed in developed countries, about 12 million more than in 2007,
while inflation has reached its lowest level since the crisis.
More
worryingly, advanced countries’ growth rates have also become more volatile.
This is surprising, because, as developed economies with fully open capital
accounts, they should have benefited from the free flow of capital and
international risk sharing – and thus experienced little macroeconomic
volatility. Furthermore, social transfers, including unemployment benefits,
should have allowed households to stabilise their consumption.
But the
dominant policies during the post-crisis period – fiscal retrenchment and
quantitative easing (QE) by major central banks – have offered little support
to stimulate household consumption, investment, and growth. On the contrary,
they have tended to make matters worse.
In the US,
quantitative easing did not boost consumption and investment partly because
most of the additional liquidity returned to central banks’ coffers in the form
of excess reserves. The Financial Services Regulatory Relief Act of 2006, which
authorised the Federal Reserve to pay interest on required and excess reserves,
thus undermined the key objective of QE.
Indeed,
with the US financial sector on the brink of collapse, the Emergency Economic
Stabilization Act of 2008 moved up the effective date for offering interest on
reserves by three years, to 1 October 2008. As a result, excess reserves held
at the Fed soared, from an average of $200bn during 2000-2008 to $1.6tn during
2009-2015. Financial institutions chose to keep their money with the Fed instead
of lending to the real economy, earning nearly $30bn – completely risk-free –
during the last five years.
This
amounts to a generous – and largely hidden – subsidy from the Fed to the
financial sector. And, as a consequence of the Fed’s interest-rate hike last
month, the subsidy will increase by $13bn this year.
Perverse
incentives are only one reason that many of the hoped-for benefits of low
interest rates did not materialise. Given that QE managed to sustain near-zero
interest rates for almost seven years, it should have encouraged governments in
developed countries to borrow and invest in infrastructure, education, and
social sectors. Increasing social transfers during the post-crisis period would
have boosted aggregate demand and smoothed out consumption patterns.
Moreover,
the UN report clearly shows that, throughout the developed world, private
investment did not grow as one might have expected, given ultra-low interest
rates. In 17 of the 20 largest developed economies, investment growth remained
lower during the post-2008 period than in the years prior to the crisis; five
experienced a decline in investment during 2010-2015.
Globally,
debt securities issued by non-financial corporations – which are supposed to
undertake fixed investments – increased significantly during the same period.
Consistent with other evidence, this implies that many non-financial
corporations borrowed, taking advantage of the low interest rates. But, rather
than investing, they used the borrowed money to buy back their own equities or
purchase other financial assets. QE thus stimulated sharp increases in
leverage, market capitalization, and financial-sector profitability.
But, again,
none of this was of much help to the real economy. Clearly, keeping interest
rates at the near zero level does not necessarily lead to higher levels of
credit or investment. When banks are given the freedom to choose, they choose
riskless profit or even financial speculation over lending that would support
the broader objective of economic growth.
By
contrast, when the World Bank or the International Monetary Fund lends cheap
money to developing countries, it imposes conditions on what they can do with
it. To have the desired effect, QE should have been accompanied not only by
official efforts to restore impaired lending channels (especially those
directed at small- and medium-size enterprises), but also by specific lending
targets for banks. Instead of effectively encouraging banks not to lend, the
Fed should have been penalizing banks for holding excess reserves.
While
ultra-low interest rates yielded few benefits for developed countries, they
imposed significant costs on developing and emerging-market economies. An
unintended, but not unexpected, consequence of monetary easing has been sharp
increases in cross-border capital flows. Total capital inflows to developing
countries increased from about $20bn in 2008 to over $600bn in 2010.
At the
time, many emerging markets had a hard time managing the sudden surge of
capital flows. Very little of it went to fixed investment. In fact, investment
growth in developing countries slowed significantly during the post-crisis
period. This year, developing countries, taken together, are expected to record
their first net capital outflow – totaling $615bn – since 2006.
Neither
monetary policy nor the financial sector is doing what it’s supposed to do. It
appears that the flood of liquidity has disproportionately gone towards
creating financial wealth and inflating asset bubbles, rather than
strengthening the real economy. Despite sharp declines in equity prices
worldwide, market capitalization as a share of world GDP remains high. The risk
of another financial crisis cannot be ignored.
There are
other policies that hold out the promise of restoring sustainable and inclusive
growth. These begin with rewriting the rules of the market economy to ensure
greater equality, more long-term thinking, and reining in the financial market
with effective regulation and appropriate incentive structures.
But large
increases in public investment in infrastructure, education, and technology
will also be needed. These will have to be financed, at least in part, by the
imposition of environmental taxes, including carbon taxes, and taxes on the
monopoly and other rents that have become pervasive in the market economy – and
contribute enormously to inequality and slow growth.
Comments
Post a Comment