Repeal and Compete
Repeal and
Compete
By: Ross Douthat
Taken from: The New York Times
Modern
conservatism, at least in its pre-Donald Trump incarnation, evolved to believe
in a marriage of Edmund Burke and Milton Friedman, in which the wisdom of
tradition and the wisdom of free markets were complementary ideas. Both, in
their different ways, delivered a kind of bottom-up democratic wisdom — the
first through the cumulative experiments of the human past, the second through
the contemporary experiments enabled by choice and competition.
In health care
policy, however, conservatives tend to simply favor Friedman over Burke. That
is, the right’s best health care minds believe that markets and competition can
deliver lower costs and better care, and they believe it even though there is
no clear example of a modern health care system built along the lines that they
desire.
The dominant systems
in the developed world, whether government-run or single-payer or
Obamacare-esque, are generally statist to degrees that conservatives deplore. A
few of them — notably Singapore’s, the beau ideal of right-wing health care
wonks — do have distinctive elements that conservatives favor. But mostly they
tend to be much more heavily regulated and subsidized than the system that
conservative health policy wonks and policy-literate Republicans would like to
see take over from Obamacare.
Which is not to
say that the conservative health policy vision lacks empirical grounding. There
is compelling evidence that markets in health care can do more to lower costs
and prices than liberals allow, and good reasons to think that free-market
competition produces more medical innovation than more socialized systems.
But still — there
is no existing system on a national scale that looks like the health care
system that Paul Ryan or Tom Price would design, no wisdom of developed-economy
experience that proves that such a system would actually keep overall costs low
and prevent too many people from being shut out of insurance markets. So
embracing even the smartest conservative Obamacare alternative requires a
not-precisely-Burkean leap of faith.
And this, in a
nutshell, is why Republicans should give serious consideration to the proposal
that Senator Bill Cassidy of Louisiana and Senator Susan Collins of Maine have
just put forward as a possible health care reform alternative.
The essence of
Cassidy-Collins, and the reason that many Republicans don’t like it, is that it
isn’t actually a full Obamacare replacement. Instead, it’s a federalist
compromise. It lets individual state governments decide whether they want to
stick with Obamacare or not, which would mean that the law would remain intact
in most blue states for the time being, while redder states would have the
opportunity to turn roughly the same amount of money (95 percent) to a
different end.
That end would
look like one of the more plausible conservative alternatives to Obamacare: a
subsidy to cover the cost of a catastrophic health insurance plan, plus a
directly funded health savings account to cover primary care.
This system could
be layered on top of the existing Medicaid expansion, replacing only the
Obamacare subsidies and exchanges, or it could replace the Medicaid expansion
as well, offering the poor and near poor the same “catastrophic insurance plus
a subsidy” as everyone else in the individual market. Either way the individual
mandate would disappear, but people would be auto-enrolled in a catastrophic
plan (with the option to opt out), meaning that coverage would be nearly
universal (thus fulfilling one of President Trump’s various promises) even
though its benefits would be less comprehensive than Obamacare’s.
Taken as a whole,
this approach distills both the promise and the peril of conservative health
care policy. The promise is that by having people pay for more of their health
care in cash and by giving them more freedom in what plans they’re allowed to
buy, you would end up with less spending, lower prices and less cost inflation.
(And you wouldn’t need the heavy, innovation-squashing price controls that
single-payer systems use to get there.)
The peril is that
there would be too wide a gap between what the money in your health savings
account covers and what you need before your catastrophic coverage kicks in. In
which case many people with consistent health care costs for chronic problems
would rack up impossible medical bills in short order.
Conservatives who
want this model to replace Obamacare nationwide believe that the promise
outweighs the risk — and this is, again, a reasonable belief. But it’s also a
belief that hasn’t been tested on any kind of sweeping, economywide scale. And
this is the advantage of Cassidy-Collins: It encourages governors and
legislators to actually put the conservative theory of health care to the test
without simply reversing the ideological colors of the great Obamacare
experiment and immediately turning the entire United States health care system
over to the right’s technocratic vision.
Of course this
would mean that Obamacare’s existing problems would persist in the states where
it continues. But those problems — the rise in premiums, the fleeing insurers,
the risk of a death spiral downstream — are not equally problematic in every
state, and they are not fiscally dangerous, as yet, on the scale that many
conservatives initially feared.
As the
conservative policy thinker Yuval Levin wrote late last year, the striking
thing about Obamacare to date is how much smaller than expected its effect on
the overall health care system has been. Fewer people are being insured on the
exchanges than liberals hoped, fewer employers are dumping high-cost employees
onto the exchanges than conservatives feared, and as a result, he writes:
The extremely serious problems we are
seeing now are within the one system that Obamacare created from scratch, the
exchange system. That system may not survive, and its condition has a lot to
teach us about the problems with liberal health economics. But it is a much
smaller system than anyone thought it would be at this point, about half the
size that C.B.O. projected, so that the effects of any failure it suffers are
likely to be more contained than anyone might have expected.
This containment
means that conservatives have room and time to be more patient, cautious and
experimental than were the Obama Democrats before them. If the Obamacare
exchanges aren’t ultimately going to work out, then allowing them to persist in
liberal states while an alternative system gets set up in red states is a
reasonable way to gradually transition from the liberal model toward the
conservative one. If the right’s wonks are right about health policy, the
Cassidy-Collins approach should — gradually — enable conservatives to prove it.
And if the right
is wrong, if its model doesn’t match reality, if people are simply miserable as
health care consumers because the system has too much of Friedman and not
enough of Burke — well, in that case both the country and conservatism will be
better off if we learn that via a voter rebellion in 10 right-leaning states,
rather than through a much more widespread backlash against a nationwide
health-insurance failure. (Which is something a president with a high
self-regard and poor approval ratings might have a particular reason to avoid.)
Between this
reasonable case and legislative reality, of course, falls a variety of shadows.
But more than for the various repeal-and-replace alternatives? I’m
not so sure.
Right now the
Cassidy-Collins compromise has few enthusiastic backers. In a few months,
however, it might turn into conservative health care reform’s best hope.
Comments
Post a Comment