Amartya Sen: Women’s Progress Outdid China’s One-Child Policy
Amartya Sen: Women’s Progress Outdid China’s
One-Child Policy
“You can stop nature,
you can stop the world, but beware of the consequences if you are not prepared,
remember Romania…”
Erreh Svaia
By: Amartya Sen
Taken From: The New York Times
The
abandonment of the one-child policy in China is a momentous change, and there
is much to celebrate in the easing of restrictions on human freedom in a
particularly private sphere of life. But we need to recognize that the big fall
in fertility in China over the decades, for which the one-child policy is often
credited, has, in fact, been less related to compulsion and much more to
reasoned family decisions in favor of a new norm of smaller families.
This
development has been particularly helped by the increasing empowerment of
Chinese women through rapid expansion of schooling and job opportunities. What
China needs now is further expansion of rethinking within families to overcome
“boy preference,” which is still widespread, despite being at odds with the
success of Chinese women.
This is a
good moment to examine what the one-child policy has done — or not done. First,
we must question the glib history that China was stuck in the adversity of high
fertility rates until the policy changed it all.
The
one-child policy was introduced in 1978. But the fertility rate had already
been falling rapidly for a decade before that — from an average of 5.87 births
per woman in 1968 to 2.98 in 1978. After that huge drop, the fertility rate
continued to fall with the new draconian policy in force, but there was no
plunge — only a smooth continuation of the falling trend that preceded the
restriction. From 2.98 in 1978, the rate has declined to 1.67 now.
Clearly,
something more than the one-child policy has been affecting birthrates in
China. Statistics that compare different countries, as well as empirical
analysis of data from hundreds of districts within India, indicate sharply that
the two most potent factors that induce fertility reduction globally are
women’s schooling and women’s paid employment.
There is no
mystery in this. The lives that are most battered by over-frequent bearing and
rearing of children are those of young mothers, and more schooling and more
gainful employment both give young women a greater voice in family decisions —
a voice that tends to work in the direction of cutting down the frequency of
births. Rapid expansion in China of education, including that of girls, and the
enhancement of job opportunities for young women occurred through a series of
decades that began well before the introduction of the one-child policy, and
they have continued robustly since.
As it
happens, fertility rate declines in China have been close to what we would
expect on the basis of these social influences alone. China often gets too much
credit from commentators on the alleged effectiveness of its harsher
interventions, and far too little for the positive role of its supportive
policies (including its heavy focus on education and health care, from which
many other countries can learn).
So while
there are harrowing reports of the hardship created in the lives of many people
in China by the enforcement of the one-child policy, it is far from clear that
this policy has had a large impact on the fertility rate of the population as a
whole.
The removal
of the one-child policy may, in fact, have been an easy choice. There is little
need for the harshness of this coercive program, given the increasing role of
reasoning about family decisions, and particularly the growing empowerment of
Chinese women.
This takes
us back to a classic disagreement between Thomas Robert Malthus and the Marquis
de Condorcet in the 18th century, at the height of the Enlightenment. Condorcet
had noted the possibility of terrible overpopulation; Malthus acknowledged that
he was following Condorcet in this, but he hugely exaggerated the danger when
he rejected Condorcet’s reassuring argument that human reasoning would produce
a corrective. Condorcet had anticipated the emergence of new norms of smaller
family size based on “the progress of reason.” Buttressed by the expansion of
education, especially for women (of which Condorcet was one of the earliest and
most vocal advocates), he argued that people would choose voluntarily to cut
the birthrate.
Reasoning
in decision making is not exclusive to the West. In China it clearly has played
a significant part already in restraining family size. It also has other
important roles to play. Despite China’s extraordinary social and economic
success (not just in economic growth), it has one of the worst records in the
world in the selective abortion of female fetuses; the number of girls born per
100 male births has been as low as 85, compared with a normal rate around 95 in
countries where there is little or no selective intervention against female
birth. Chinese women have made huge progress in most spheres of life, but
traditional “boy preference” is still rampant. However, legal remedies against
sex-selective abortion, like outlawing it, have been ineffective wherever they
have been tried.
What is
needed is more reasoning, aided by further use of women’s empowerment, against
such an arbitrary and dehumanizing bias. Such a change has, in fact, been very
successfully achieved in South Korea, which once also had a very low ratio of
girls to boys at birth. The cultivation of active public reasoning and wider
understanding of the demands of gender equity have produced a huge change
there.
China needs
to rely even more on the force of reasoning, rather than on legal compulsion.
The removal of the one-child policy is surely an important move in that
direction. The fact that China’s demographic history over the last half-century
gives firm evidence of what Condorcet called “the progress of reason” certainly
gives ground for optimism. This is all the more important, since China has more
challenges to address in this productive way.
Comments
Post a Comment