The New Spirit of Postcapitalism
The New Spirit of Postcapitalism
By: Paul
Mason
Taken from:
IPS Journal
The streets
are full of young people (and not just students)—sitting, sipping drinks,
gazing more at laptops than into each other’s eyes, talking quietly about
politics, making art, looking cool.
A time
traveller from their grandparents’ youth might ask: when is lunchtime over? But
it’s never over because for many networked people it never really begins. In
the developed world, large parts of urban reality look like Woodstock in
permanent session—but what is really happening is the devalorisation of
capital.
Sure,
somewhere on the edge of a big city, there is always a financial district where
regimented people, uniformly dressed, pursue work-like activity frantically
and, in their few hours of release, hit the gym treadmills so that the
adrenaline never stops.
But just 20
years after the rollout of broadband and 3G telecoms, information resonates
everywhere in social life: work and leisure have become blurred; the link
between work and wages has been loosened; the connection between the production
of goods and services and the accumulation of capital is less obvious.
Ask a
mainstream economist what is going on and they might reply ‘consumption’ or
‘leisure time’. The postcapitalism thesis rests on the idea that there is
something more than that. Digital networks, which Schumpeterian economists
assumed would usher in a new and dynamic era of capitalism, have instead begun
to break down traditional patterns in four identifiable ways.
First,
there is the zero-marginal-cost effect, whereby the production cost of
information goods falls, under conditions of free markets and competition,
towards zero — and where, as a result, production costs in both manufacturing
and services also fall.
Second is
the potential for the decisive automation of physical work — 47 per cent of
jobs or 43 per cent of tasks, depending on the research.
Third is
the network effect — what tech corporations experience as ‘increasing returns
to scale’. On a vast scale networks create positive externalities, where the
ownership rights over the utility produced are not preordained by a
factory-like division between employer and worker.
Finally,
there is the potential democratisation of information itself. A glitch
discovered in a piece of software tonight can be remedied on every instance of
that software by tomorrow morning; a mistake in Wikipedia can be spotted and
corrected instantaneously by the wisdom of crowds.
A new kind
of system
The
postcapitalist project is founded on the belief that, inherent in these
technological effects lies a challenge to the existing social relations of a
market economy, and in the long term, the possibility of a new kind of system
that can function without the market, and beyond scarcity.
But during
the past 20 years, as a survival mechanism, the market has reacted by creating
semi-permanent distortions which — according to neoclassical economics — should
be temporary.
In response
to the price-collapsing effect of information goods, the most powerful
monopolies ever seen have been constructed. Seven out of the top ten global
corporations by market capitalisation are tech monopolies; they avoid tax,
stifle competition through the practise of buying rivals and build ‘walled
gardens’ of interoperable technologies to maximise their own revenues at the
expense of suppliers, customers and (through tax avoidance) the state.
Because
information machines can replace humans faster than they create new, skilled
jobs, millions of low-paid jobs have been created which do not need to exist.
Instead of concentrating work into short bursts, to maximise productivity, the
blurring of work and leisure time has been encouraged and consumption
activities (booking a holiday, arranging a date, messaging friends) has been
tolerated within work time, because this maximises consumption and
personal-data production.
In response
to the network effects, a new model — the platform monopoly — has sprung up,
attracting billions in offshore capital that cannot be productively invested
elsewhere. The entire business model of such corporations is to charge economic
rents and — as with the others — strangle the competition, which in the case of
ride-hailing apps is the traditional taxi business and the city government.
In response
to the democratising effects of infotech, vast and growing information
asymmetries have been created.
Neither
competition nor regulation has so far put a stop to this fourfold process of
consolidation and sclerosis. Features like monopoly, under-employment,
rent-seeking and information asymmetry, assumed by classical economics to be
temporary, have begun to look like permanent requirements for the 21st-century
private sector. Instead of a fourth industrial revolution, a parasitic,
dysfunctional infocapitalism has been created whose monopoly profits and
anti-competitive behaviour are so intrinsic to the system that they cannot be
challenged.
Embryonic
forms
In a
medieval city, the embryonic forms of bourgeois society were effectively
invisible. If we picture 14th-century Paris at the time of Etienne Marcel’s
revolt, the power lay in the great hôtels of the provincial feudal lords, in
the monastery, in the myriad churches and in the university. Together they
formed a machine for administering and validating the wealth produced on rural
estates. Cross-border banking was effectively a secret service, reliant on
religious orders for storage depots and complex forward contracts to get around
the ban on usury. Even the actual bourgeoisie refused to back Marcel’s attempt
to impose the rule of law on the king, so alien did the concept seem.
But from
the vantage point of knowing what became of feudalism we can see the guilds,
the proto-banks, the cross-border trade networks and scientific thinking within
the medieval university as a kind of ‘capitalism in embryo’.
If I return
to the scene in Barcelona, the microcosmic changes in everyday life now have a
different meaning. The free time is a product of under-employment. To keep
people servicing capital through interest payments, apps and e-commerce, they
must have a job, a credit card and a cellphone — no matter how poor they are.
The under-employed, poor, information-rich young person is the avatar of both
the malaise and the possibility of a solution.
People
survive the creation of what David Graeber calls ‘bullshit jobs’ by blurring
work and leisure, and by living frugally — because though monopolies are
racking up high prices for their goods, the zero-marginal-cost effect allows
one to live cheaply on the basics. Most people are using open-source or very
cheap software without even knowing it. The monopolies, in addition, give away
information services in return for the right to farm our personal data. Life is
lived by ducking and diving between rent-seeking monopoly services: Uber,
Airbnb, Tinder.
You can see
the same kind of life in any big city — but I chose Barcelona because, together
with Amsterdam and a few other self-described ‘fearless cities’ under left
hegemony, it has, for now, a political leadership which understands the
potential of an economy based on open-source software, information symmetry and
the abolition of monopolies and economic rent.
Under Ada
Colau, who became mayor after leading a housing-rights movement, the city has
dedicated 22 staff and €16 million over four years to fostering social,
co-operative and solidarity economics. Hackers, housing activists and
environmentalists hold office and senior technocratic jobs.
The city
has used its €1bn a year procurement budget to force outsourcers to accept the
principle that data are a public good, not to be farmed at zero cost by tech
giants. By consciously promoting alternative forms of ownership, and by
preferring local, co-operative tech firms over the multinationals, the city now
has more than 4,800 registered co-operative businesses.
It looks as
unspectacular and fragile as early capitalism did amid the splendour of late
feudalism. The task of turning it into something bigger requires, first, a
revolution in government intervention, whereby the state consciously shapes the
creation of an open-source, collaborative and non-market sector of the economy.
Secondly,
these alternative forms of business model must evolve so as to scale — so that
their best practices can be turned into drag-and-drop solutions for start-ups.
Thirdly,
there must be access to finance, though in a different form than that encountered
in the tech start-up world.
Finally, a
revolution in human attitudes is required.
There is a
great passage in Max Weber’s The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism
where he describes the take-off point of industrial capital. A young man from one
of the ‘putting out’ families in the textile trade instilled rigour into his
cottage-based workers, sought economies of scale and cut out all middlemen. As
a result, the idyllic life of rural spinners and weavers collapsed. Weber
concludes: ‘It was not generally in such cases a stream of new money invested
in the industry which brought about this revolution … but the new spirit, the
spirit of modern capitalism, had set to work.’
If you look
closely enough at the attitudes of young people brought up in an entirely
digital world, you see a new spirit at work.
The
bourgeois would call it fecklessness; the big consumer brands call it
‘pro-sumption’. Sit in a squat, a collaborative workspace or a state funded
arts lab in one of these cities and you can see it is instead, quite
consciously, a determination to live ‘despite’ the implicit assumptions of
mainstream economics.
Comments
Post a Comment