The Economic Consequences of Austerity
The Economic Consequences of Austerity
By: Amartya
Sen
Taken from:
New Statesman
On 5 June 1919,
John Maynard Keynes wrote to the prime minister of Britain, David Lloyd George,
“I ought to let you know that on Saturday I am slipping away from this scene of
nightmare. I can do no more good here.” Thus ended Keynes’s role as the
official representative of the British Treasury at the Paris Peace Conference.
It liberated Keynes from complicity in the Treaty of Versailles (to be signed
later that month), which he detested.
Why did
Keynes dislike a treaty that ended the state of war between Germany and the
Allied Powers (surely a good thing)?
Keynes was
not, of course, complaining about the end of the world war, nor about the need
for a treaty to end it, but about the terms of the treaty – and in particular
the suffering and the economic turmoil forced on the defeated enemy, the
Germans, through imposed austerity. Austerity is a subject of much contemporary
interest in Europe – I would like to add the word “unfortunately” somewhere in
the sentence. Actually, the book that Keynes wrote attacking the treaty, The
Economic Consequences of the Peace, was very substantially about the economic
consequences of “imposed austerity”. Germany had lost the battle already, and
the treaty was about what the defeated enemy would be required to do, including
what it should have to pay to the victors. The terms of this Carthaginian
peace, as Keynes saw it (recollecting the Roman treatment of the defeated
Carthage following the Punic wars), included the imposition of an
unrealistically huge burden of reparation on Germany – a task that Germany
could not carry out without ruining its economy. As the terms also had the
effect of fostering animosity between the victors and the vanquished and, in
addition, would economically do no good to the rest of Europe, Keynes had nothing
but contempt for the decision of the victorious four (Britain, France, Italy
and the United States) to demand something from Germany that was hurtful for
the vanquished and unhelpful for all.
The
high-minded moral rhetoric in favour of the harsh imposition of austerity on
Germany that Keynes complained about came particularly from Lord Cunliffe and
Lord Sumner, representing Britain on the Reparation Commission, whom Keynes
liked to call “the Heavenly Twins”. In his parting letter to Lloyd George, Keynes
added, “I leave the Twins to gloat over the devastation of Europe.” Grand
rhetoric on the necessity of imposing austerity, to remove economic and moral
impropriety in Greece and elsewhere, may come more frequently these days from
Berlin itself, with the changed role of Germany in today’s world. But the
unfavourable consequences that Keynes feared would follow from severe – and in
his judgement unreasoned – imposition of austerity remain relevant today (with
an altered geography of the morally upright discipliner and the errant to be
disciplined).
Aside from
Keynes’s fear of economic ruin of a country, in this case Germany, through the
merciless scheduling of demanded payments, he also analysed the bad
consequences on other countries in Europe of the economic collapse of one of
their partners. The thesis of economic interdependence, which Keynes would
pursue more fully later (including in his most famous book, The General Theory
of Employment, Interest and Money, to be published in 1936), makes an early appearance
in this book, in the context of his critique of the Versailles Treaty.
“An
inefficient, unemployed, disorganised Europe faces us,” says Keynes, “torn by
internal strife and international hate, fighting, starving, pillaging, and
lying.” If some of these problems are visible in Europe today (as I believe to
some extent they are), we have to ask: why is this so? After all, 2015 is not
really anything like 1919, and yet why do the same words, taken quite out of
context, look as if there is a fitting context for at least a part of them
right now?
If
austerity is as counterproductive as Keynes thought, how come it seems to
deliver electoral victories, at least in Britain? Indeed, what truth is there
in the explanatory statement in the Financial Times, aired shortly after the
Conservative victory in the general election, and coming from a leading
historian, Niall Ferguson (who, I should explain, is a close friend – our
friendship seems to thrive on our persistent disagreement): “Labour should
blame Keynes for their election defeat.”
If the
point of view that Ferguson airs is basically right (and that reading is shared
by several other commentators as well), the imposed austerity we are going
through is not a useless nightmare (as Keynes’s analysis would make us believe),
but more like a strenuous workout for a healthier future, as the champions of
austerity have always claimed. And it is, in this view, a future that is
beginning to unfold already in our time, at least in Britain, appreciated by
grateful voters. Is that the real story now? And more generally, could “the
Heavenly Twins” have been right all along?
There are
many odd features of the experience of the world since the crisis of 2008,
beginning in the United States. One of them is that what began as a clear
failure of the market economy (particularly fed by misbehaving financial
institutions) soon looked like a problem of the overstretched role of the
state. The crisis, when it came, was seen – rightly, I believe – as a failure
of the operation of the private financial institutions, and led to a huge
demand for reinstating some of the state regulations, particularly of the
financial markets, that had been gradually eliminated in the US economy through
piecemeal eradication (beginning in the Reagan presidency but continuing
through Democratic administrations). However, after the massive decline in 2008
of financial markets and of business confidence had been halted and to some
extent reversed through the intervention of the state, especially through
stimulating the economy, often paid for by heavy public borrowing, the state
had large debts to deal with. The demand for a smaller government which had
begun earlier, led by those who were sceptical of extensive public services and
state provision, now became a loud chorus, with political leaders competing
with each other in frightening people with the idea that the economy could not
but collapse under the burden of public debt.
Similarly,
at the international level, the global free fall following the 2008 crisis was
largely halted by the move, under the visionary leadership of Gordon Brown, for
a meeting of the governments of the newly formed G20 in April 2009 in London,
each promising to do its best not to feed the downward spiral by domestic
complicity. This turned a page in the history of the crisis successfully, but
soon the story changed, with the governments being asked to get out of the way
before they ruined healthy business activities.
Turning to
the management of debts, suddenly the idea of austerity as a way out for the
depressed and heavily indebted economies became the dominant priority of the
financial leaders of Europe. Those with an interest in history could easily see
in this a reminder of the days of the Great Depression of the 1930s when
cutting public expenditure seemed like a solution, rather than a problem. This
is, of course, where Keynes made his definitive contribution in his classic
book, the General Theory, in 1936. Keynes ushered in the basic understanding
that demand is important as a determinant of economic activity, and that
expanding rather than cutting public expenditure may do a much better job of
expanding employment and activity in an economy with unused capacity and idle
labour. Austerity could do little, since a reduction of public expenditure adds
to the inadequacy of private incomes and market demands, thereby tending to put
even more people out of work. There is, of course, more to Keynes’s full theory
than that, but the common-sense summary just presented is gist enough.
However,
the financial leaders of Europe had a different reading – from Keynes and from
a great many mainstream economists – of what was needed, and they were not
going to budge from their understanding. As it is quite common these days to
blame economists for failing to see the real world, I take this opportunity to
note that very few professionally trained economists were persuaded by the
direction in which those in charge of European finances decided to take Europe.
The European debacle demonstrated, in effect, that you do not need economists
to generate a holy mess: the financial sector can generate its own gory
calamity with the greatest of elegance and ease. Further, if the policy of austerity
deepened Europe’s economic problems, it did not help in the aimed objective of
reducing the ratio of debt to GDP to any significant extent – in fact,
sometimes quite the contrary. If things have started changing, over the past
few years, even if quite slowly, it is mainly because Europe has now started to
pursue a hybrid policy of somewhat weakened fiscal austerity with monetary
expansion. If that is a half-hearted gesture towards Keynes, the results are
half-hearted, too.
There is,
in fact, plenty of evidence in the history of the world that indicates that the
most effective way of cutting deficits is to resist recession and to combine
deficit reduction with rapid economic growth. The huge deficits after the
Second World War were easily tamed with fast economic growth in the postwar
years (I will come back to this issue later). Something similar happened during
the eight years of Bill Clinton’s presidency of the United States, when Clinton
began with a huge deficit and ended with none, thanks largely to rapid economic
growth. Again, the much-praised reduction of the Swedish budget deficit during
1994-98 occurred in a period of fairly fast growth of GDP. Despite political
deadlocks and a largely non-functional Congress, the United States has been
much smarter than Europe, on this occasion, in making use of this central
understanding. The ratio of deficit to GDP has fallen in the US thanks to
economic growth, which – rather than austerity – is of course the well-tried
way of achieving the desired result.
Had the
policy leaders of Europe (adherents of a peculiarly narrow view of financial
priority) allowed more public discussion, rather than taking unilateral
decisions in secluded financial corridors – encouraging no public discussion –
it is possible that the policy errors could have been prevented, through the
standard procedures of deliberation, scrutiny and critique. It is remarkable
that this has not happened in the continent that gave the world the basic ideas
of institutional democracy. The big epistemic failure in missing the lessons of
the past on revival, deficit reduction and economic growth is not only a matter
of wrong turns taken by the financial leaders, including the European Central Bank,
but also of the democratic deficit in Europe today. It is no consolation that
most of the governments in the eurozone that deployed the strategy of austerity
lost office in public elections that followed. Democracy should be about
preventing mistakes through participatory deliberations, rather than about
making heads roll after mistakes have been made. This is one of the reasons why
John Stuart Mill saw democracy as “government by discussion” (a phrase coined,
along Millian lines, by Walter Bagehot), and this demands discussion preceding
public decisions, rather than following them.
How was it
possible, it has to be asked, for the basic Keynesian insights and analyses to
be so badly lost in the making of European economic policies that imposed
austerity? Some of the dominant figures in the financial world have had a
long-standing scepticism of the economic relations on which Keynes focused
which is being emended only now, with reality checks being made in observations
of the penalty of the neglect of Keynesian relations. The bold plan by the new
president of the European Central Bank, Mario Draghi, which we have every
reason to welcome, to deliver a trillion euros of “quantitative easing” (not
unlike expanding the money supply) – with decisive expansionary effect – is a
result of that belated recognition which is slowly changing the European
Central Bank: that expansion rather than contraction is what the economy needs.
If failing
to understand some basic Keynesian relations is a part of the explanation of
what happened, there was also another, and more subtle, story behind the
confounded economics of austerity. There was an odd confusion in policy
thinking between the real need for institutional reform in Europe and the
imagined need for austerity – two quite different things. There can be little
doubt that Europe has needed, for quite some time, many serious institutional
reforms – from the avoidance of tax evasion and the fixing of more reasonable
retiring ages to sensible working hours and the elimination of institutional
rigidities, including those in the labour markets. But the real (and strong)
case for institutional reform has to be distinguished from an imagined case for
indiscriminate austerity, which does not do anything to change a system while
hugely inflicting pain. Through the bundling of the two together as a kind of
chemical compound, it became very difficult to advocate reform without
simultaneously cutting public expenditure all around. And this did not serve
the cause of reform at all.
This is a
simple enough point, and it is surprising how difficult it has proved to be to
get this across. I have to confess to humbling failure in making an impact on
the policymakers through my efforts on this by addressing the European
Commission, the IMF, the Bank for International Settlements, and joint meetings
of the World Bank and the OECD, starting in the summer of 2009.
An analogy
can help to make the point clearer: it is as if a person had asked for an
antibiotic for his fever, and been given a mixed tablet with antibiotic and rat
poison. You cannot have the antibiotic without also having the rat poison. We
were in effect being told that if you want economic reform then you must also
have, along with it, economic austerity, although there is absolutely no reason
whatsoever why the two must be put together as a chemical compound. For
example, having sensible retiring ages, which many European countries do not (a
much-needed institutional reform), is not similar to cutting severely the
pensions on which the lives of the working poor may depend (a favourite of
austeritarians). The compounding of the two – not least in the demands made on
Greece – has made it much harder to pursue institutional reforms. And the
shrinking of the Greek economy under the influence mainly of austerity has
created the most unfavourable circumstances possible for bold institutional
reforms.
Another
counterproductive consequence of the policy of imposed austerity and the
resulting joblessness, for Keynesian reasons, has been the loss of productive
power – and over time the loss of skill as well – resulting from continued
unemployment of the young. The rate of youth unemployment is astonishingly high
in many European countries today; more than half the young people in Greece
have never experienced having a job. The very process of the formation of human
capability, on which Adam Smith put emphasis as the real engine of economic
success and human progress, has been quite badly mishandled through the tying together
of uncalled-for austerity (which no country really needed) with necessary
reform (which many European countries did need).
More than
200 years ago, Adam Smith specified with much clarity in The Wealth of Nations
how to judge the good functioning of a well-run economy. Good political
economy, Smith argued, has to have “two distinct objects”: “first, to provide a
plentiful revenue or subsistence for the people, or more properly to enable
them to provide such a revenue or subsistence for themselves; and secondly, to
supply the state or commonwealth with a revenue sufficient for the publick
services”.
The father
of modern economics, and the pioneering champion of the market system, did not
have any doubt why the role of the state fits integrally into the demands of a
good society. Public reasoning over generations has increasingly vindicated and
supported Adam Smith’s broad vision. There are good reasons to think that it
would have done the same today had open and informed public dialogue been given
a proper chance, rather than being ruled out by the alleged superiority of the
judgements of financial leaders, with their breathtakingly narrow view of human
society and a basic lack of interest in the demands of a deliberative
democracy.
It is
certainly true that the policy of austerity has been advertised as the reason
behind the comparative success of the British economy. This comparison is,
however, with Europe, which has been in a bigger hole than Britain, with a more
vigorous imposition of austerity, particularly in some countries (Greece is of
course the extreme example of that – with the big shrinking of its economy,
rather than having economic growth). The relatively positive growth in recent
years does not make Britain’s overall experience of growth over the period of
austerity particularly impressive, if we look beyond Europe. Not only is the
price-adjusted GDP per capita in Britain today still lower than what it was
before the crisis in 2008, but also, in the period of recovery from the low of
2009, GDP per capita has risen far more slowly in the UK than in the US and
Japan (not to mention some of the faster-growing Asian economies).
Could the
British voters, then, have missed the real story? That is possible, and I shall
come to that possibility presently, but the voting figures do not quite bring
out a groundswell of approval in favour of austerity. There is no question that
Labour had a severely bad election, and has lost ground, not just in Scotland,
and must rethink its priorities as well as strategies quite radically. But the
parties forming the coalition government – the Conservatives and Liberal
Democrats – had support from more than 59 per cent of the total vote in the
election before last in 2010 (that is, before they sprang the surprise of
austerity on the British public); yet the coalition parties together have
managed to get only around 45 per cent in this election – after the experience
of austerity. Not quite a heady success for the vote-getting ability of
austerity. The Tories did get a clear majority of seats on their own (and have
good reason to celebrate that outcome), but this achievement came with only 37
per cent of the votes. The success here is just like that of the
Hindutva-oriented BJP in India in the elections last year, when it got 31 per
cent of the ballots cast but a substantial majority of parliamentary seats. Before
we start getting our economic theories from the reading of election results, we
have to scrutinise a bit more the message that comes through from the votes and
the seats in the constituency-based electoral systems that the UK and,
following it, India happen to have.
What is not
in doubt, however, is that the general public in the UK, following the crisis
of 2008, has become increasingly nervous about the size of the public debt and
also about the ratio of public debt to GDP. What is overlooked here is that
while a national debt may have many costs (and it is not paranoiac to keep
tracking it), it is not quite like an individual person’s debt, which is owed
to someone else (someone quite different). An internal national debt is mainly
owed to another person in the same economy. Figures of seemingly large public
debt may be handy enough to frighten a population with imagined stories of
ruining the future generations, but the analysis of public debt demands more
critical thinking than that, rather than drawing on a misleading analogy with
private indebtedness.
There are
two distinct issues here. First, even if we want to reduce public debt quickly,
austerity is not a particularly effective way of achieving this (which the
European and British experiences confirm). For that, we need economic growth;
and austerity, as Keynes noted, is essentially anti-growth. Second, what is
also important to note is that while panic may be easy to generate, the
existence of panic does not show that there is reason for panic. No less
importantly, the public has not always been scared stiff by the size of the
public debt. The public debt-to-GDP ratio was very considerably larger in
Britain in every year for two decades, from the mid-1940s to the mid-1960s,
than it has been at any time since the crisis of 2008. And yet there was no
panic then (when Britain was confidently establishing the welfare state), in
contrast to the confused anxiety, not to mention the orchestrated fear, that
seems to run down the spine of the terrorised British today, making austerity
look like a fitting response.
When
Britain went for pioneering the welfare state and established the National
Health Service, among other ways of expanding the public services, with Aneurin
Bevan inaugurating the Park Hospital in Manchester on 5 July 1948, the ratio of
debt to GDP was larger than 200 per cent, much more than twice what it has been
at any point in recent years. Had the British public been as successfully
frightened about the debt ratio in those days, the NHS would never have been
born, and the great experiment of having a welfare state in Europe (from which
the whole world from China, Korea and Singapore to Brazil and Mexico would
learn) would not have found a foothold. A decade later, when Harold Macmillan,
as a buoyant new prime minister, told the British people in July 1957 that they
had “never had it so good”, the size of government debt was more than 120 per
cent of GDP – immensely higher than the ratio of roughly 70 per cent in 2010
when Gordon Brown was accused of mortgaging Britain’s future by profligacy.
The scare
was not there from the late 1940s through the 1960s, with Labour as well as
Conservative governments in office, perhaps because the scarers were more
scarce then. And armed with good public services and a flourishing market
economy, Britain steadily reduced its debt-to-GDP ratio through economic
growth, while establishing the welfare state and a huge array of new public
services.
Public
knowledge and understanding are indeed central to the ability of a democratic
government to make good policies. The Economic Consequences of the Peace ends
by pointing to the connection between epistemology and politics, and arguing
that we can make a difference to the world only by (in Keynes’s words) “setting
in motion those forces of instruction and imagination which change opinion”.
The last sentence in the book affirmed his hope: “To the formation of the
general opinion of the future I dedicate this book.” In that dedication, there
is enlightenment as well as optimism, both of which we strongly need today.
Comments
Post a Comment