China’s Boldest Experiment
China’s
Boldest Experiment
By: Dani
Rodrik
Taken from:
Project Syndicate
Forty years
ago this month, China’s leaders set the country on a path of reform that has
produced the most dramatic economic transformation in history. Mao Zedong had
died two years earlier, in 1976, and the newly rehabilitated Deng Xiaoping
succeeded in stamping his vision of economic development and modernization on
the Third Plenary Session of the Eleventh Central Committee held in December
1978. In the four decades since, China has transformed itself into an economic
powerhouse, portending an equally momentous makeover of the global economy and
geopolitics.
China’s
reforms started in agriculture, where the crushing burden of state controls was
relaxed. Through the dual-track pricing mechanism, farmers were given market
incentives. The household responsibility system allowed them greater control
over the land they worked. Farmers responded quickly, increasing their
efficiency and output.
Reforms
were subsequently broadened and extended into other areas. Non-agricultural
production incentives were bolstered through a hybrid form of ownership called
Township and Village Enterprises (TVEs). As the reforms spread to cities, state
enterprises gained more autonomy and were encouraged to become entrepreneurial.
Incentives were created for provinces and localities to invest and spur
economic growth. And the growth of Special Economic Zones (SEZs) in the 1990s
turned China decisively toward integration with the world economy.
The general
thrust of these reforms was to increase the economy’s market orientation and
external openness. But while China’s share of international trade and private
investment grew and that of the state sector steadily shrank in relative terms,
the authorities retained a firm hand in managing the economy. Economic
restructuring and diversification were promoted through a range of industrial
policies. Foreign investors were required to enter into joint ventures with
domestic firms and to increase the use of local inputs. The exchange rate and
international financial flows remained controlled for the most part.
Through it
all, China’s leadership did not follow any guidebook and resolutely marched to
the beat of its own drummer. Reform was guided by neither communist teachings
nor free-market dogma. If senior policymakers followed one overarching
principle, it was what might be called “pragmatic experimentalism.” As Deng
famously said, what mattered was not the color of the cat, but whether it
caught the mice.
Given the
peculiarities of China’s experience, it is not surprising that there remains
considerable debate about the lessons to be drawn from it. For many in the
West, China demonstrates the benefits of reliance on markets and economic
liberalization. Yet if China were an economic basket case today, I suspect the
same voices would be quick to attribute the failure to the continued
intrusiveness of the Chinese state. For others, China demonstrates the
intrinsic superiority of the state-led model. Yet many of the same policies,
such as dual-track pricing or domestic content requirements, have failed in
other settings.
These
opposing perspectives can be reconciled. China has not violated the tenets of
mainstream economics so much as it has offered a master class in applying them
creatively in complicated political and economic terrain. Dual-track pricing
provided market incentives at the margin without undermining the fiscal
revenues. TVEs spurred private entrepreneurship, despite weak frameworks for
property rights and contract enforcement. SEZs spurred exports and foreign
investment without undermining employment among protected state enterprises.
Industrial policies allowed infant industries to internalize learning
spillovers. In short, China represents the triumph of practical economics – in
which second-best strategies, market failures, general equilibrium, and political
economy prevail – over the simplistic reasoning of Econ 101.
The biggest
test for the Chinese model may be yet to come. Throughout the country’s
economic transformation, the political primacy of the Communist Party of China
was never in question. But outside observers expected that continued economic
development would eventually lead to political liberalization. Instead, under
President Xi Jinping, China has taken a decidedly more authoritarian turn. That
is bad news for the hundreds of millions of Chinese whose political freedoms
are being ever more tightly circumscribed.
Political
repression could be bad news for the economy as well, for at least two reasons.
First, people’s ability to speak freely provides an advance-warning mechanism
for policies that might eventually fail, enabling the authorities to change
course before more damage is done. Second, political competition provides
institutional mechanisms for channeling opposition, which otherwise might spill
over to the streets and fuel civil disorder.
China’s
leaders seem to be betting that they can avoid both types of problems. They
believe they have their ears sufficiently to the ground that they can remain
responsive to any brewing discontent. And they hope they can exercise social
control through facial recognition and other new technologies, which they have
taken the lead in deploying.
The
conventional wisdom among social scientists is that the demands of advanced
economies and growing middle classes can be met only through greater political
freedoms and competition. The Chinese political elite are skeptical, and not
without reason. When they look at the West nowadays, they see populism,
demagoguery, and deep divisions, rather than harmonious, inclusive societies.
Their attempt to combine a high-growth, technologically sophisticated economy
with reinforced authoritarianism is perhaps their most ambitious experiment to
date.
Comments
Post a Comment